More Neo-Nazi Neoconnery


Summary of Cotton’s remarks:

1. Putin is Hitler! We need to be more like Hitler and start an unprovoked attack on Russia*

1.1 Munich! Munich! Munich!

2. Russia is an enemy.

3. Ukraine is under occupation.

4. Estonia and Latvia are worth conducting military operations against!

5. There are still 100s of thousands of refugees left to be made homeless!

6. Appeasement everywhere! Georgia didn’t attack first with its tanks!

7. I can’t pronounce Russian names while spouting on about the country!

8. Krim was invaded! It totally wasn’t the will of the Crimean people to join Russia.

9. I am the new Hitler! Operation Barbarossa 2.0 now!

10. No American arms have been sent to Ukraine!

11. No, seriously, when I said Operation Barbarossa 2.0, I meant it.

12. Also, destroy the Syrian gov’t, and make up phony excuses to prevent the removal of Iranian sanctions.

13. Operation Barbarossa 2.0! Literally! In Eastern Ukraine!

*The alternative to Munich was… what? An unprovoked invasion of Germany.

I want the guy who said you don’t have to pass an IQ test to be a Senator back!!!




Screenshot (63)
It’s one thing to call for nuclear war against Turkey and the Turkish people (as I do). It is quite another to call for conventional war against the second-longest established nuclear power, as well as the only country with a nuclear stockpile even remotely close to the size and capability of that of the U.S.

Obviously, I cannot say the neocons are totally equivalent to neo-Nazis. The neocons are philosemitic (if not actually Semitic); the neo-Nazis are antisemitic. The neocons descend from Trotsky and his concept of world revolution; neo-Naziism descends from German racialism and militarism, as well as from local racial tensions. The neocons promote dildocracy; the neo-Nazis are generally against it. But in at least one instance, they are peas in a pod.

Obvious Point

The national government deficit is 14% of GDP. Inflation is 14%. The rate of Real GDP growth is 0%. What is the national debt-GDP ratio doing?*

The national government deficit is 5% of GDP. Inflation is 2%. The rate of Real GDP growth is 1% per year. What is the national debt-GDP ratio doing?**

*Staying flat.
**Increasing by 2 percentage points per year.

This is why looking at the national debt-GDP ratios of the US and UK in the 1970s and 1980s and making conclusions about fiscal conservatism is hopelessly misleading. Doubly so, in fact, due to the close relationship between unemployment and the national government deficit combined with the Phillips Curve. Complaining about “soaring deficits” in the 1980s due to the “soaring” debt-GDP ratios may be outright lying.

I’m looking at you, Noah Smith.

BTW, the first four sentences of the above-linked-to post are utter falsehoods, on the level of claiming North Vietnam lost the Vietnam War.

Good Minds Think Alike

Pretty much my plan for Syria. Let’s hope this video gets half a million views, at least.

Obviously, mine would also involve either nuking Turkey if it doesn’t cooperate, or, in the remote case it does, at least temporarily totally closing, and, preferably, temporarily totally evacuating the entire length of the Syro-Turkish border, and permanently expelling Turkey from NATO, as well as removing Erdogan from power and trying him for crimes against humanity. Also, Obama. I’d also consider settling the refugees in southern Turkey permanently, as compensation, if they absolutely refuse to return to Assad-land (for understandable reasons). Obviously, no First-World country should be accepting Syrian refugees. Forcing Turkey to pay reparations, no matter how tempting, is inadvisable -taxed men revolt, dead men stay dead. This is why it is better to nuke Turkey than to force it to pay reparations.

Totally destroying the Islamic State in less than three days via a three-pronged attack from Iraqi Kurdistan, the southern Euphrates, and the Tell Abyad-Raqqa road is a given. Panama fell quicker, despite a larger army and more military equipment.

Coates Refutes Himself


, , ,

Nine days ago, a dude known as Coates wrote another long-ish tirade about his race and its travails. It’s not what you think.

Unlike Coates’ earlier major Atlantic piece, The Case for Reparations, which was trite and totally unnecessary for me to have read, I found this latest piece of Coates fairly awesome. In it, he makes a stirring case for the expansion of the prison state, explaining why the vast majority of those incarcerated today basically deserve it, why Daniel Patrick Moynihan was right about everything except opposing mass incarceration, and why reparations for slavery won’t fix anything -while probably not intending to! Were the good Steve Sailer to have written it, except for some sentences and concluding sections, and, of course, the broader tone and use of examples, the piece would be largely intact.

Choice quotes (all filled with awesome!):

As the civil-rights movement wound down, Moynihan looked out and saw a black population reeling under the effects of 350 years of bondage and plunder. He believed that these effects could be addressed through state action. They were—through the mass incarceration of millions of black people.

In 1984, 70 percent of all parolees successfully completed their term without arrest and were granted full freedom. In 1996, only 44 percent did. As of 2013, 33 percent do.

The carceral state has, in effect, become a credentialing institution as significant as the military, public schools, or universities—but the credentialing that prison or jail offers is negative.

Deindustrialization had presented an employment problem for America’s poor and working class of all races.

“Roughly half of today’s prison inmates are functionally illiterate,”

Kelly Miller, who was then a leading black intellectual and a professor at Howard University, presaged the call for blacks to be “twice as good,” asserting in 1899 that it was not enough for “ninety-five out of every hundred Negroes” to be lawful. “The ninety-five must band themselves together to restrain or suppress the vicious five.”

So even as violent crime declined between 1925 and 1940, Louisiana’s incarceration rate increased by more than 50 percent.

The cure, as Nixon saw it, was not addressing criminogenic conditions, but locking up more people. “Doubling the conviction rate in this country would do far more to cure crime in America than quadrupling the funds for [the] War on Poverty,” he said in 1968.

The justification for resorting to incarceration was the same in 1996 as it was in 1896.

The argument that high crime is the predictable result of a series of oppressive racist policies does not render the victims of those policies bulletproof.

In prison, Odell has repeatedly attempted to gain his G.E.D., failing the test several times. “My previous grade school teacher noted that I should be placed in special education,” Odell wrote in a 2014 letter to his lawyer. “It is unclear what roll childhood lead poisoning played in my analytical capabilities.”

In 2006, Martin O’Malley (who’s currently vying to be the Democrats’ nominee for president in 2016) defeated Ehrlich to become governor, but he took an even stricter stance on lifers than his predecessor, failing to act on even a single recommendation of the Parole Commission.

One of my great irritants is how so much of our discussions on race and racism proceed from the notion that American history begins in the 1960s. The discussions around Detroit is the obvious example. There is a popular narrative which holds that Detroit was a glorious city and the riots ruined it. Thomas J. Sugrue’s The Origins Of the Urban Crisis does a great job at dialing back this idea and pointing to the long arc of the city’s decline.

The fires of 1967 conveniently obscured those perils. But the structural problems, along with the wave of deindustrialization, were what gifted America with the modern “Negro problem.” By the 1970s, the government institution charged with mediating these problems was, in the main, the criminal-justice system.

“African Americans in our data are distinct from both Latinos and whites,” Robert Sampson told me. “Even when we control for marital status and family history of criminality, we still see these strong differences. The compounded deprivation that African Americans experience is a challenge even independent of all the characteristics we think are protective.”

Moynihan’s observation about the insufficiency of civil-rights legislation has been proved largely correct.

“The Negro Family” is a flawed work in part because it is a fundamentally sexist document that promotes the importance not just of family but of patriarchy, arguing that black men should be empowered at the expense of black women.

There is, of course, nothing wrong with discouraging degeneracy by promoting male-headed households.

“It would be difficult to overestimate the degree to which young well educated blacks detest white America.”

Moynihan ominously cited a “rather pronounced revival—in impeccably respectable circles—of the proposition that there is a difference in genetic potential” between the two races.

Crime really did begin to rise during the early 1970s. But by this point, Moynihan had changed. According to the Moynihan of the Nixon era, middle-class blacks were not hardworking Americans attempting to get ahead—they were mobsters demanding protection money in exchange for the safety of America’s cities. And the “unusually self-damaging” black poor were hapless tools, the knife at the throat of blameless white America.

One does not build a safety net for a race of predators. One builds a cage.

In 1900, the black-white incarceration disparity in the North was seven to one —roughly the same disparity that exists today on a national scale.

This statement links to a really interesting article, of which the choice graphs are these:

Screenshot (60)

Screenshot (61)

In 1972, the U.S. incarceration rate was 161 per 100,000—slightly higher than the English and Welsh incarceration rate today (148 per 100,000). To return to that 1972 level, America would have to cut its prison and jail population by some 80 percent. The popular notion that this can largely be accomplished by releasing nonviolent drug offenders is false—as of 2012, 54 percent of all inmates in state prisons had been sentenced for violent offenses.

One 2004 study found that the proportion of “unambiguously low-level drug offenders” could be less than 6 percent in state prisons and less than 2 percent in federal ones.

There is no reason to assume that a smaller correctional system inevitably means a more equitable correctional system. Examining Minnesota’s system, Richard S. Frase, a professor of criminal law at the University of Minnesota, found a state whose relatively sane justice policies give it one of the lowest incarceration rates in the country—and yet whose economic disparities give it one of the worst black-white incarceration ratios in the country.

And so it is not possible to truly reform our justice system without reforming the institutional structures, the communities, and the politics that surround it.

And should crime rates rise again, there is no reason to believe that black people, black communities, black families will not be fed into the great maw again.

The graphs are also informative, and help illustrate Coates’ case, as I’ve put it, well.

There are obviously problematic parts to Coates’ piece -he’s still considers “an autocratic Vladimir Putin” to be the same as Russia’s entire criminal justice system (which is obviously much worse than America’s). Believe me, Russia’s criminal justice system was bad before Putin, is bad today, and will continue to be bad after Putin. Coates’ use of international comparisons is likely specious. According to Coates, Canada’s incarceration rate never strongly changed from 1960 to today. The statistics seem to back him up on this fact.

Canada’s total crime rate seems to have fallen at pretty much the same rate in the 1990s and the 2000s, while the U.S.’s fell faster during the 1990s, when the U.S.’s incarceration rate was still skyrocketing. The sources I’ve found for Canadian violent crime are contradictory.  Either Canada’s violent crime rate was always much higher than that of the U.S. and never really fell since its early 1990s peak, and also rose much faster than that in the U.S. during the late 1980s (even while Canada experienced a much milder crack pandemic and decline), when the U.S. incarceration rate was still skyrocketing, or something entirely different happened- Canada’s violent crime rate was always lower than that of the U.S. and experienced pretty much the same trends as that of the U.S., only on a milder scale. I have no clue which to judge as more believable.

Meanwhile, Canada’s homicide rate did not decline as much as in the U.S. during the 1990s and 2000s, while it stayed stable during the 1980s, as in the U.S. Canada offers a useful test case for lack of mass incarceration, leading me to take the claim that increased incarceration is of only minimal importance in explaining the rise and fall of North American crime much more seriously, but it hardly refutes the general point that incarceration reduces crime by taking criminals off the streets.

But perhaps the worst part of it is this ludicrous piece of bullshit:
“There’s very little evidence that it brought down crime—and abundant evidence that it hindered employment for black men, and accelerated the kind of family breakdown that Clinton and Moynihan both lamented.”

-Never mind the dubious claim (which I have not yet researched in depth) that there’s very little evidence mass incarceration brought down crime- Coates cites zero evidence that it has in any way affected “the kind of family breakdown that Clinton and Moynihan both lamented”, much less accelerated it. Most of the collapse of the American Black family took place before American mass incarceration. Most of the collapse of the American White family took place after its beginning. The correct comparison is not between incarcerated men and non-incarcerated men, but incarcerated and non-incarcerated men of similar age and criminal background. In fact, it was during the period 1982-1988 (you have to choose your years wisely here; the 1980-1982 recessions hurt Blacks far more than Whites) that the Black and White male employment/non-incarcerated-population ratios converged most strongly. The most reasonable explanation for the collapse of the Black (and later White) family is contraception and abortion. Yeah, I know, the Catholic Church is right on this one, as is Roissy!

There are, of course, other errors:
“Even in the booming ’90s, when nearly every American demographic group improved its economic position, black men were left out.”
-The common opinion at the time was pleasure that black men (at least, the non-incarcerated ones) weren’t left out during the 1990s. And, indeed, they weren’t:



The claim that “This might well have been true as a description of drug enforcement policies, but it was not true of actual drug abuse: Surveys have repeatedly shown that blacks and whites use drugs at remarkably comparable rates.” is also ridiculous, as anyone who has any basic intuition knows. “Surveys” are unreliable (i.e., they lead to wrong results) and misleading (they ignore the length and pattern of drug use). See the link above in this paragraph!

The claim of “persistent racism” in Detroit (an 80+%-Black city!) and in the rest of America is utter crap, but fairly ignorable tripe. If anything, the problem in Detroit is “persistent racism” against Whites, which has, quite fortunately, been alleviated to some extent in the past few years. Referencing “Jim Crow” in the context of Detroit is also nonsensical, as Jim Crow never existed there. Blaming mass incarceration for “ensuring that the peril continues” is also nuts. Mass incarceration is a response to peril; it is not a net contributor to it. Incarceration, as Coates has already pointed out, is a signalling mechanism. And there’s nothing wrong with reducing the noise-signal ratio. Bruce Western’s claims are total nonsense. If Blacks were Chinese (or at least Vietnamese), they wouldn’t be disproportionately incarcerated. The idea wages for Black men have remained stagnant “largely due to our correctional policy” is the opposite of the truth, as basic supply-and-demand would easily illustrate. A scarcity of labor results in an increase in wages, not a decrease, as the Medieval Plague showed.

Indeed, the vast majority of U.S. Blacks do not see themselves as treated unfairly by the police, and this variable remains near an all-time high:

Look at all the racism!

Combined with Ryan Faulk’s new and true demonstration that Black-White school funding differences in the Jim Crow South had, if anything, a slight equalizing impact on the present-day Black-White school test score gap, Coates’ piece powerfully shows that the end of Jim Crow really didn’t change much for the vast majority of anyone except those Black Americans in the right-most third of the Black American IQ bell curve. Indeed, Black optimism regarding the future of Black-White relations peaked during the Civil Rights era and fell behind that of Whites during the 1990s:

This suggests two things:
1. Obstacles to Black advancement are few.
2. There’s most likely never going to be a solution to Black-White relations in America. Not in five years, not in fifty years, and probably not in five hundred years.

Jim Crow is dead. Equal treatment (and, occasionally, preferential treatment in favor of Blacks) is the law. Convergence is nowhere in sight.

There is no evidence Blacks can build first-world countries when not under White supervision.* There is no evidence of any consistent trend of convergence between White and Black American social outcomes since a generation ago. There is no evidence anything outside eugenics can change that**. Reparations are a farce. Systemic change is a farce. Ending mass incarceration is a danger (see quotes on the composition of the prison population above).

*The Bahamas, the only Black-majority first-world country, became independent in 1973 and had a higher Real GDP per capita in 1969 than today.

**Yes, moving to opportunity had some success in improving individual poor Black social outcomes, probably due mostly to the effects of the beneficiaries getting a better preparation for High School and a Bachelor’s Degree. But even if the fallacy of composition does not apply in this case (a highly dubious assumption), and education is not largely a pure signaling competition (also a highly dubious assumption), a one-time level change a consistent trend of convergence does not make.

On the Morality of Ad-Blocking


, ,

In ancient times (the print newspaper era, about the 16th-17th century) the idea of advertising as a way of financially supporting media was invented*. People looked at whatever the print newspapers contained, and advertisers paid the newspapers for their inclusion of advertisements in their newspapers, thus keeping the cost to the consumer low. You couldn’t really automatically block the ads, but you could cover them up with spare paper and glue. Cutting them out would usually just cut out another story in the paper, so most people didn’t do that. Likewise, the radio era (about the 1920s) led to the rise of sound advertising. Again, people could skip the ads, but if they did, they might miss some of the actual programming, so most people didn’t. The same continued with the rise of television. The rise of the Internet, however, led to three things:

  1. The ability of users to automatically block ads without any effort.
  2. The rise of unskippable video ads (rarely used, but existent).
  3. The fusion of multiple pop-up, text and video ads on webpage sidebars, thus causing a maximum amount of intrusion to the viewer of content.

Today, on the most visited news sites on the Internet, the typical user using a typical web browser without any add-ons or tracking protection lists installed (e.g., Microsoft Edge today) would experience a morass of unwanted ads, slow loading times, and numerous tracking scripts having nothing to do with displaying content. Unless one is contractually obligated to do so, there is no reason to allow all those requests for information and advertising display to be fulfilled by your browser. It’s worse than useless -it takes up your bandwith, tracks your behavior without your desire, and displays you advertisements you won’t click on. The idea that all this gunk is necessary to fund the online content you need is nonsense -the most advertising-laden websites are precisely those which have the basest, most worthless, most sensationalist content on the Internet. On the other hand, those sites least dependent on advertising are also those least prone to descend into content whoredom (yes, even the occasionally awesome Slate Star Codex has sometimes descended to this, quite possibly due to its mild ad displays).

In fact, I strongly encourage you to use the Adblock Plus and NoScript add-ons for Firefox, Chrome, and (to be released) Edge and various cookie managers for all these browsers. For Internet Explorer, I strongly recommend you use the Tracking Protection Lists (excepting the Truste list, which is made by advertisers) in the IE gallery, as these are some of the only add-ons which work in both the Metro and Desktop modes and successfully block most trackers and ads on the web.

If you are not obligated to, why slow your browser down while using excess bandwith? I know ads exist on this site; I don’t get any money from them. Block them. If WordPress shuts down, I’ll move elsewhere. If I wanted money, I would have set up a donate button on this website for you to give me some. Though I might conceivably do this later, I simply don’t have the necessity for it now. There’s nothing wrong with a fundraising drive, just as long as the money is going to someone you know is worthy of it.

Ad-blocking is only immoral when it is explicitly prohibited as part of a contract.

*Yes, advertising also existed in the Helleno-Roman era, but printing didn’t exist at the time.

How High Would a Federal Minimum Wage Have To Be to Cause Mass Unemployment?



Answer: pretty high (at least $12), but see below for qualifications and doubts. The highest Federal minimum wage in U.S. history, relative to the average manufacturing wage, was the modern-day equivalent of $12. It took effect in October 1939. However, this only applied to employees engaged in interstate commerce or the production of goods for interstate commerce, so it isn’t clear what percentage of the U.S. workforce was affected by it:
Screenshot (49)
Note: to convert minimum wage from portion of prevailing average manufacturing wage into approximate present dollar equivalent, multiply the portion by twenty or twenty-one.

However, assuming this correlation:
Screenshot (50)
(R² = 0.83841884602996, using a power trendline) was sound for the time, this is what the portion of hourly paid wage and salary workers working at or below the highest Federal minimum wage would have looked like before 1978, if the power trendline correlation used for the average hourly wage in the U.S. is applied to the average hourly manufacturing wage (not quite the same thing, especially after 2006):
Screenshot (52)
I strongly doubt that over 50% of hourly workers in 1969 or over 65% in 1950 had their pay determined by the maximum hourly Federal minimum wage of the time. How many workers actually had their pay determined by the various minimum wages of the time would be interesting to see. Also, it’s not just the Federal minimum wage that matters -state and local minimum wages matter just as much, perhaps, even more.

In the old days, the highest U.S. minimum wage was more restricted in application than it is today, yet, far higher relative to prevailing average wages. The minimum wage only became fully unified for farm and nonfarm workers in 1978, when farm work had become all but irrelevant in America. However, it is clear that the minimum wage has generally had little effect on broad unemployment trends in the United States: the modern era of high over-27 week unemployment began only in 1974: precisely when the minimum wage relative to the prevailing average wage came down from its secular heights in the 1950s and 1960s. Also, note that the largest minimum wage increase in post-WW II U.S. history; that in January 1950, seemed to have no substantial effect on the natural rate of unemployment (it also coincided with, but certainly did not cause, the largest RGDP/worker boom in post-WWII U.S. history).

There were four periods in U.S. history when minimum wage hikes occurred around recessions: the minimum wage hikes around the recession of 1990, which pushed the percentage of hourly paid wage and salary workers paid at or below the minimum wage up to 1986 levels, the minimum wage hikes around the Great Recession, which pushed the percentage of hourly paid wage and salary workers paid at or below the minimum wage up to 1998 levels, and the minimum wage hikes of 1945 and 1974.

Thus, I doubt the Federal minimum wage is very important in explaining broad unemployment trends from 1939 to today. But this is hardly an exhaustive study on this topic, and does not look at the actual prevalence of the various state, Federal, and local minimum wages for the various occupations to which it applied from 1939 to today. Such a study would be very useful in explaining how high a minimum wage would cause an appreciable amount of unemployment, especially for low-skilled workers.

By the way, also see this post for the Federal minimum wage growing faster than productivity for most workers who are actually paid the minimum wage or below, and why the Far Left is generally deceptive in its claims about the minimum wage and productivity. Also, I have noticed a small upward trend with average wages for leisure and hospitality workers in the late 1960s which I’m fairly, but not quite, sure has nothing to do with the expansion of the applicability of the Federal minimum wage:

Screen Shot 2015-09-06 at 23.25.29

Of course, I completely oppose the minimum wage, as well as any other price control during peacetime. The minimum wage, despite its seemingly small effect on U.S. unemployment, is never a good thing on net, as it interferes with the proper functioning of the free market and is fundamentally against Americans’ freedom without any clear net social benefit. The full long-term effects of price controls and their interactions with markets are more difficult to predict than most think.

Update: Here’s a graph of the convergence of the rural and maximum Federal minimum wages. Also, there’s a graph of teen unemployment divided by middle-aged unemployment in the comments. It doesn’t strongly support the idea that the minimum wage ever did much of anything.

Update #2: The minimum wage hike of 1950 (largest of all time) was intended for all workers covered by the fair labor standards act; roughly half of wage and salary workers. So probably something like 30% of wage and salary workers had their pay directly determined by the Federal minimum wage at the time-higher than the level in the 1970s, but nowhere near 70%.

Is There Evidence Aggregate Demand Played a Role in EZ Crisis?


, , ,

Yes, there is:
Screenshot (48)
This is a scatterplot of Eurozone countries. Horizontal axis is change in RGDP over period specified in the data; vertical axis is change in the GDP deflator over period specified in the data. Periods specified in the data are variable, and are meant to approximate the timing of the last Eurozone recession in each country, or, if no secondary recession hit the country, slowdown after 2009-10 recovery.
Data here and is entirely from the St. Louis Fed fred2 site. Any errors are mine.
Note, if you remove Austria, Estonia, and Greece, the R-squared falls to .0538, not nearly as impressive.
An explanation: if aggregate demand did not play a role in the Eurozone double-dip recession (2011-13, generally), there should have been no correlation of decline in RGDP and growth in the GDP deflator during that period. If the major role was due to aggregate supply, there should have been a positive correlation of decline in RGDP and growth in the GDP deflator. As you can see, that is clearly not the case.
However, note that the largest gap between changes in the price level and changes in Real GDP occur in Greece, Portugal, and Italy-the three countries most strongly affected by the Eurozone crisis in terms of Real GDP, while Estonia, France, and Germany, which did not suffer nearly as much in 2011-13, have the smallest gaps between changes in the price level and changes in real GDP. For some reason, the entirety of the Eurozone is suffering from really sticky prices, with none having a rate of RGDP change higher than the rate of GDP deflator change. Price and wage controls in Portugal, Greece, and Italy would probably help alleviate their situations, as these countries have no sovereign monetary policy, and must rely on falling prices to combat the money illusion if NGDP falls. Note that regaining competitiveness via internal devaluation is not necessarily the issue here; trade is not a huge component of the Greek economy (gross exports only constitute about a third of GDP; net exports far less).